averse$6200$ - definition. What is averse$6200$
Diclib.com
قاموس ChatGPT
أدخل كلمة أو عبارة بأي لغة 👆
اللغة:

ترجمة وتحليل الكلمات عن طريق الذكاء الاصطناعي ChatGPT

في هذه الصفحة يمكنك الحصول على تحليل مفصل لكلمة أو عبارة باستخدام أفضل تقنيات الذكاء الاصطناعي المتوفرة اليوم:

  • كيف يتم استخدام الكلمة في اللغة
  • تردد الكلمة
  • ما إذا كانت الكلمة تستخدم في كثير من الأحيان في اللغة المنطوقة أو المكتوبة
  • خيارات الترجمة إلى الروسية أو الإسبانية، على التوالي
  • أمثلة على استخدام الكلمة (عدة عبارات مع الترجمة)
  • أصل الكلمة

%ما هو (من)٪ 1 - تعريف

PEOPLE'S TENDENCY TO PREFER AVOIDING LOSSES TO ACQUIRING EQUIVALENT GAINS, A BEHAVIOR FIRST IDENTIFIED BY AMOS TVERSKY AND DANIEL KAHNEMAN
Loss averse; Neural basis of loss aversion
  • A graph of perceived value of gain or loss vs. strict numerical value of gain or loss. A loss of $0.05 is perceived as a much greater loss than of a comparable gain of $0.05.
  • The effect of losses on the allocation of attention according to the loss attention account.

Risk aversion         
PREFERENCE AGAINST RISK, A COMMON HUMAN BEHAVIOR OF ATTEMPTING TO LOWER UNCERTAINTY AND AVOID RISK
Risk Aversion; Risk-aversion; Absolute risk aversion; Arrow-Pratt measure; Coefficient of absolute risk aversion; Coefficient of relative risk aversion; Decreasing absolute risk aversion; Increasing absolute risk aversion; Constant absolute risk aversion; Increasing relative risk aversion; Decreasing relative risk aversion; Constant Relative Risk Aversion; Risk averse; CARA utility; Risk tolerance; Risk tolerant; Risk-tolerant; Risk-averse; Log utility; Risk attitude; Co-efficient of absolute risk aversion; Risk Tolerance; Relative risk aversion; Risk aversion scale; Risk aversion (Economics); Risk aversion (economics)
In economics and finance, risk aversion is the tendency of people to prefer outcomes with low uncertainty to those outcomes with high uncertainty, even if the average outcome of the latter is equal to or higher in monetary value than the more certain outcome. Risk aversion explains the inclination to agree to a situation with a more predictable, but possibly lower payoff, rather than another situation with a highly unpredictable, but possibly higher payoff.
Carry-I         
  • Front and rear views of the ''Carry-I'' book-size LAN station diskless workstation, based on an Intel 80286 processor.
  • Power supply unit for the ''Carry-I''. Note the detailed pinout diagram for the power connector.
FT-6200
The Carry-I was a book-size workstation produced by Flytech Technology of Taiwan, circa 1991. It was available in multiple configurations; ranging from Intel 8088 based XT-compatible models, to a high end model powered by a 16 MHz 386SX and featuring an 80MB hard drive.
Power Macintosh 6200         
SERIES OF PERSONAL COMPUTERS BY APPLE
Macintosh Performa 6214CD; Macintosh Performa 6200; Performa 6200; Power Macintosh 6300; Power Macintosh 6300/120; Power Macintosh 6300/160; Power Macintosh 6360; Macintosh Performa 6360; Performa 6300; Macintosh Performa 6300; Macintosh Performa 6200CD; Macintosh Performa 6320CD; Macintosh Performa 6205CD; Macintosh Performa 6310CD; Macintosh Performa 6300CD; Macintosh Performa 6290CD; Macintosh Performa 6260CD; Macintosh Performa 6230CD; Macintosh Performa 6220CD; Macintosh Performa 6218CD; Macintosh Performa 6216CD; Macintosh Performa 6210CD; Performa 6320CD; Performa 6310CD; Performa 6300CD; Performa 6290CD; Performa 6200CD; Performa 6205CD; Performa 6210CD; Performa 6216CD; Performa 6214CD; Performa 6218CD; Performa 6220CD; Performa 6230CD; Performa 6260CD; Performa 6360
The Power Macintosh 6200 (also sold under variations of the name Performa 6200, Performa 6300 and Power Macintosh 6300) is a series of personal computers designed, manufactured, and sold by Apple Computer from May 1995 to July 1997. The 6200 is the PowerPC-based replacement for the Quadra 630, with the same form factor and price range.

ويكيبيديا

Loss aversion

Loss aversion is the tendency to prefer avoiding losses to acquiring equivalent gains. The principle is prominent in the domain of economics. What distinguishes loss aversion from risk aversion is that the utility of a monetary payoff depends on what was previously experienced or was expected to happen. Some studies have suggested that losses are twice as powerful, psychologically, as gains. Loss aversion was first identified by Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman.

Loss aversion implies that one who loses $100 will lose more satisfaction than the same person will gain satisfaction from a $100 windfall. In marketing, the use of trial periods and rebates tries to take advantage of the buyer's tendency to value the good more after the buyer incorporates it in the status quo. In past behavioral economics studies, users participate up until the threat of loss equals any incurred gains. Recent methods established by Botond Kőszegi and Matthew Rabin in experimental economics illustrates the role of expectation, wherein an individual's belief about an outcome can create an instance of loss aversion, whether or not a tangible change of state has occurred.

Whether a transaction is framed as a loss or as a gain is important to this calculation. The same change in price framed differently, for example as a $5 discount or as a $5 surcharge avoided, has a significant effect on consumer behavior. Although traditional economists consider this "endowment effect", and all other effects of loss aversion, to be completely irrational, it is important to the fields of marketing and behavioral finance. Users in behavioral and experimental economics studies decided to cease participation in iterative money-making games when the threat of loss was close to the expenditure of effort, even when the user stood to further their gains. Loss aversion coupled with myopia has been shown to explain macroeconomic phenomena, such as the equity premium puzzle.